What CSS & PMS Qualifiers Say! Read Now

Feudalism’s Grip: Why Pakistan’s Land Reforms Failed

Sadia Jabeen

Sadia Jabeen is Sir Syed Kazim Ali 's student and writer, empowering aspirants.

View Author

21 July 2025

|

338

Despite land reform efforts by Ayub Khan and Zulfikar Ali Bhutto, feudal influence persists in Pakistani politics due to inherent legislative loopholes, compromised implementation, and the socio-political adaptability of landed elites. The reforms did not fundamentally alter socio-economic dependencies in rural areas, allowing the feudal system to maintain its grip on political structures and outcomes.

Feudalism’s Grip: Why Pakistan’s Land Reforms Failed

The persistent influence of the feudal system on Pakistan's political landscape, despite land reform initiatives by Ayub Khan and Zulfikar Ali Bhutto, remains a critical impediment to genuine democratic development and equitable socio-economic progress. While these reforms aimed to curtail the power of large landowners and redistribute land, their impact was largely superficial. A combination of inherent loopholes in the legislation, weak implementation, the adaptive capacity of the feudal elite, and enduring socio-economic dependencies ensured that the foundational structures of feudal power remained largely intact, continuing to shape political outcomes.

Follow Cssprepforum WhatsApp Channel: Pakistan’s Largest CSS, PMS Prep Community updated

Led by Sir Syed Kazim Ali, Cssprepforum helps 70,000+ aspirants monthly with top-tier CSS/PMS content. Follow our WhatsApp Channel for solved past papers, expert articles, and free study resources shared by qualifiers and high scorers.

Follow Channel

The historical context of land ownership in the regions constituting Pakistan is deeply rooted in colonial-era policies that often reinforced the power of large landholders. At independence in 1947, Pakistan inherited an agrarian economy dominated by a powerful feudal class, whose extensive landholdings translated directly into social control and political leverage. This class effectively controlled rural populations, influencing voting patterns and ensuring their representation in legislative assemblies. The land reforms introduced by Ayub Khan in 1959 under Martial Law Regulation 64, and subsequently by Zulfikar Ali Bhutto in 1972 under Martial Law Regulation 115 and again in 1977, were ostensibly designed to break this nexus. These reforms sought to impose ceilings on land ownership, abolish certain feudal privileges like jagirs, and provide greater security of tenure to tenants, with the overarching goal of creating a more egalitarian rural society and a more pluralistic political sphere.

Enduring Shadows: The Resilience of Feudal Power

Despite the proclaimed objectives, the land reforms initiated by both Ayub Khan and Zulfikar Ali Bhutto ultimately failed to dismantle the entrenched feudal system or significantly diminish its pervasive influence on Pakistani politics. Several intertwined factors contributed to this outcome, ensuring the landed elite's continued dominance.

Inherent Loopholes and Generous Exemptions

A primary reason for the limited success of the land reforms lay in their design. Both Ayub Khan's and Bhutto's reforms incorporated numerous exemptions and loopholes that large landowners skillfully exploited. Ayub's West Pakistan Land Reforms Regulation 1959 set a ceiling of 500 acres of irrigated land or 1,000 acres of unirrigated land. However, generous allowances for orchards -up to 150 acres, stud farms, and Shikargahs -hunting grounds, along with provisions for transferring land to family members, including female dependents, significantly diluted the impact. Many landlords, forewarned of impending reforms, quickly subdivided their estates among relatives and even fictitious inheritors. Bhutto's 1972 reforms, while reducing the ceiling to 150 irrigated acres and 300 unirrigated acres, also contained similar provisions for transfers and exemptions. For instance, an additional allowance was made for owning a tractor or tubewell. These "benami" -fictitious name- transactions and strategic use of exemptions meant that the actual amount of land resumed and redistributed was far less than anticipated, allowing feudal families to retain control over vast swathes of agricultural land and, consequently, their socio-political influence.

Deficiencies in Implementation and Bureaucratic Sympathies

The effective implementation of any land reform program hinges on a robust and impartial administrative machinery. In Pakistan, this was severely lacking. The bureaucracy, particularly at the local level, was often deeply intertwined with the landed elite, either through kinship, shared class interests, or susceptibility to their influence and pressure. Land records were frequently poorly maintained, outdated, or deliberately manipulated, making it difficult to accurately assess land ownership and enforce ceilings. The Land Commission established to oversee the reforms often lacked the requisite autonomy, resources, and political backing to challenge powerful feudal interests. Consequently, the process of land resumption and redistribution was slow, fraught with corruption, and unevenly applied. The political will to rigorously enforce the reforms waned, particularly when faced with organized resistance from influential landlords who were also key political players or supporters. This weak enforcement mechanism ensured that even the modest goals of the reforms were not fully realized.

Feudal Adaptation and Political Entrenchment

The feudal class in Pakistan demonstrated remarkable resilience and adaptability in the face of these reforms. Rather than fading away, many landlords diversified their economic interests, investing in urban property, businesses, and industry, while retaining their rural power base. Crucially, they entrenched themselves deeply within the political system. Recognizing the changing dynamics, feudal elites actively participated in electoral politics, leveraging their traditional influence over rural voters to secure seats in provincial and national assemblies. They became indispensable to successive civilian and military governments, offering bloc votes and local control in exchange for patronage and the protection of their interests. This co-optation meant that any political party or regime seeking power often had to accommodate feudal interests, thereby undermining any serious attempt to challenge their dominance. The feudal lords transformed from traditional power brokers into modern politicians, effectively using democratic structures to perpetuate their influence.

Persistent Socio-Economic Dependencies and the Patron-Client Nexus

The land reforms did little to alter the fundamental socio-economic dependencies that bind tenants and landless peasants to large landowners. In many rural areas, landlords continued to be the primary source of credit, employment, and dispute resolution. The lack of alternative economic opportunities, limited access to education and healthcare, and the persistence of debt bondage meant that tenants remained reliant on their landlords for survival. This deep-seated dependency translated directly into political subservience, with tenants often compelled to vote according to the dictates of their landlords. The reforms failed to empower tenants sufficiently or create viable, independent small-farmer economies on a large scale. Without genuine economic emancipation, the political leverage of the feudal class over vast segments of the rural population remained largely unchallenged, ensuring their continued ability to mobilize votes and maintain political power. The Hari Commission Report in Sindh, even before these major reforms, had highlighted the dire conditions of tenants, a situation that reforms only marginally improved.

The Ambiguous Role of the Green Revolution

Concurrent with these reform periods, Pakistan experienced the Green Revolution, which introduced high-yield crop varieties, fertilizers, and mechanization. While this significantly boosted agricultural productivity, its benefits were not evenly distributed. Larger landowners, with greater access to capital and credit, were better positioned to adopt these new technologies. This often led to increased land concentration in some areas, as smaller, less efficient farmers were bought out or further marginalized. Mechanization, such as the increased use of tractors, also reduced the demand for tenant labor, sometimes weakening the bargaining position of tenants rather than empowering them. While the Green Revolution transformed agricultural practices, it did not fundamentally alter the power structures; in some instances, it may have even reinforced the economic clout of the established landed aristocracy, allowing them to further consolidate their influence by controlling modern agricultural inputs and outputs.

Join 3-Day Free Orientation for CSS/PMS English Essay & Precis Course

Learn to Qualify for CSS 2026/27 & PMS with Sir Syed Kazim Ali’s free 3-day online orientation. Learn essay & precis writing. Limited seats available; register via WhatsApp by June 29!

Join Now

The failure of Ayub Khan's and Bhutto's land reforms to eradicate feudal influence stems from a complex interplay of legislative compromises, implementation failures, and the sheer adaptive capacity of the landed elite. The reforms were often politically motivated gestures rather than deep-rooted structural changes. The state lacked the sustained political will to confront the powerful feudal lobby, which was, and remains, an integral part of Pakistan's power structure. Consequently, these reforms often treated the symptoms rather than the disease of concentrated land ownership and its associated political power.

In retrospect, the land reforms undertaken by Ayub Khan and Zulfikar Ali Bhutto, while representing attempts to address land inequality, were ultimately insufficient to dislodge the deep-rooted influence of the feudal system on Pakistani politics. The combination of cleverly designed loopholes, weak and often compromised implementation machinery, the adeptness of feudal lords in navigating and co-opting political systems, and the persistence of socio-economic dependencies in rural areas ensured their continued dominance. True agrarian reform requires more than just legislative enactments; it demands unwavering political commitment, robust institutional support for enforcement, comprehensive measures to empower tenants and small farmers economically, and a diversification of rural economies. Until such holistic changes are pursued, the shadow of feudalism will continue to loom large over Pakistan's political development, hindering the emergence of a truly representative and equitable democratic order.

500 Free Essays for CSS & PMS by Officers

Read 500+ free, high-scoring essays written by officers and top scorers. A must-have resource for learning CSS and PMS essay writing techniques.

Explore Now

How we have reviewed this article!

At HowTests, every submitted article undergoes a careful editorial review to ensure it aligns with our content standards, relevance, and quality guidelines. Our team evaluates the article for accuracy, originality, clarity, and usefulness to competitive exam aspirants. We strongly emphasise human-written, well-researched content, but we may accept AI-assisted submissions if they provide valuable, verifiable, and educational information.
Sources
Article History
Update History
History
21 July 2025

Written By

Sadia Jabeen

M.Phil. Botany

Author

Reviewed by

Sir Syed Kazim Ali

English Teacher

The following are the references used in the editorial “Feudalism’s Grip: Why Pakistan’s Land Reforms Failed”.

History
Content Updated On

1st Update: July 21, 2025

Was this Article helpful?

(300 found it helpful)

Share This Article

Comments